Economic and Marketing Information for Indiana Farmers (Mar. 29, 1968) |
Previous | 1 of 4 | Next |
|
|
Loading content ...
Economic and Marketing Information FOR INDIANA FARMERS Prepared by the Agricultural Staff of Purdue University, Lafayette, Indiana March 29, 1968 INDIANA FARMERS Alternatives for MAINTAINING THE FAMILY FARM* Farmers today are much concerned about the future organization of agriculture. Their loss of managerial independence is distintegrating the family farm in ways not fully visible from trends in farm numbers and sizes. Farmers see at stake their freedom and economic status relative to other groups. Farmers still have some options for retaining and perhaps advancing the entrepreneural independence inherent in family farm agriculture if they desire to do so. In terms of public policy, the most forceful argument for saving the family farm is to support decentralized decision-making and diffused economic power in our society. The Changing Structure of Farming Rapid change in number and sizes of farms is an important cause of anxiety among farmers and disturbances in rural communities, but this alone is not the central issue. In size of business, most farm production units can still be classified as family farms. That is, farm families provide a large part of the labor except for seasonal work and transitional stages in the families. Furthermore, research studies relating cost per unit to size have generally shown that all of the economies of size can be achieved by modern and fully mechanized one-man and * This article was condensed from a speech presented at Farm Science Days, Purdue University, January 9, 1968. by Paul L. Farris, Agricultural Economics two-man farms. Although technology will not remain constant in the future, 10 or 20 years from now we will probably still count large numbers of family size farms. This is not to say that adequate size of business is not important. While the total number of farms in the United States dropped from 4-1 million in 1959 to 3-25 million in 1966, those with annual sales of $20,000 or more rose from 325,000 to 527,000. These farms accounted for about half of the value of all farm products sold in 1959 and about two-thirds in 1966. Large farms also earned higher average rates per unit of labor and capital employed in farming than did smaller farms. Many operators of small units recognize that they must grow larger to earn returns more nearly comparable with returns to similar resources employed outside of agriculture. Hence, farmers compete intensely for additional land. The share of business done by large farms is expected to continue rising, but the increase will come mainly from greater numbers of farms in large size classes rather than large farms in existence growing to massive size. Loss of Managerial Independence When we turn to entrepreneural functions, we often see more profound change. In producing some commodities, farmers are subject to increasing degrees of managerial supervision from suppliers and creditors. In selling, farmers are faced with increasing pressures and incentives to standardize product quality and to gear large and regular volumes of product supplies to particular market outlets. Options in selling are being narrowed further by a reduced number of buyers and by disappearance of traditional open markets. Many producers are finding it more and more desirable to have a specific sales outlet in sight before making production decisions. How much managerial independence has been lost by farmers varies widely among enterprises and areas of the country. The shift of entrepreneural functions off the farm has been greatest for poultry and some specialty crops. Farmers in the Midwest appear to have retained more decision-making latitude than farmers in other areas, but their traditional types of operations are being strongly challenged by integrated production-marketing systems in other sections. Other Characteristics of the Agricultural Industry Other well-known characteristics of agriculture intensify changes in number, size, and managerial independence of farmers as well as bring repeated pressures on earnings. Uncoordinated output frequently results in supplies greater than the market will absorb without sharp declines in prices. Quantities taken by the domestic market are little influenced by income or price changes, and foreign markets are
Object Description
Title | Economic and Marketing Information for Indiana Farmers (Mar. 29, 1968) |
Purdue Identification Number | UA14-13-econ196803 |
Date of Original | 1968 |
Publisher | Purdue University. Agricultural Extension Service |
Subjects (LCSH) |
Farm produce--Indiana--Marketing Agriculture--Economic aspects--Indiana |
Genre | Periodical |
Collection Title | Extension Economic & Marketing Information (Purdue University. Agricultural Extension) |
Rights | Copyright Purdue University. All rights reserved. |
Coverage | United States - Indiana |
Type | text |
Format | JP2 |
Language | eng |
Repository | Purdue University Libraries |
Date Digitized | 05/01/2015 |
Digitization Specifications | Original scanned at 400 ppi on a BookEye 3 scanner using Opus software. Display images generated in Contentdm as JP2000s; file format for archival copy is uncompressed TIF format. |
URI | UA14-13-econ196803.tif |
Description
Title | Economic and Marketing Information for Indiana Farmers (Mar. 29, 1968) |
Purdue Identification Number | UA14-13-econ196803 |
Transcript | Economic and Marketing Information FOR INDIANA FARMERS Prepared by the Agricultural Staff of Purdue University, Lafayette, Indiana March 29, 1968 INDIANA FARMERS Alternatives for MAINTAINING THE FAMILY FARM* Farmers today are much concerned about the future organization of agriculture. Their loss of managerial independence is distintegrating the family farm in ways not fully visible from trends in farm numbers and sizes. Farmers see at stake their freedom and economic status relative to other groups. Farmers still have some options for retaining and perhaps advancing the entrepreneural independence inherent in family farm agriculture if they desire to do so. In terms of public policy, the most forceful argument for saving the family farm is to support decentralized decision-making and diffused economic power in our society. The Changing Structure of Farming Rapid change in number and sizes of farms is an important cause of anxiety among farmers and disturbances in rural communities, but this alone is not the central issue. In size of business, most farm production units can still be classified as family farms. That is, farm families provide a large part of the labor except for seasonal work and transitional stages in the families. Furthermore, research studies relating cost per unit to size have generally shown that all of the economies of size can be achieved by modern and fully mechanized one-man and * This article was condensed from a speech presented at Farm Science Days, Purdue University, January 9, 1968. by Paul L. Farris, Agricultural Economics two-man farms. Although technology will not remain constant in the future, 10 or 20 years from now we will probably still count large numbers of family size farms. This is not to say that adequate size of business is not important. While the total number of farms in the United States dropped from 4-1 million in 1959 to 3-25 million in 1966, those with annual sales of $20,000 or more rose from 325,000 to 527,000. These farms accounted for about half of the value of all farm products sold in 1959 and about two-thirds in 1966. Large farms also earned higher average rates per unit of labor and capital employed in farming than did smaller farms. Many operators of small units recognize that they must grow larger to earn returns more nearly comparable with returns to similar resources employed outside of agriculture. Hence, farmers compete intensely for additional land. The share of business done by large farms is expected to continue rising, but the increase will come mainly from greater numbers of farms in large size classes rather than large farms in existence growing to massive size. Loss of Managerial Independence When we turn to entrepreneural functions, we often see more profound change. In producing some commodities, farmers are subject to increasing degrees of managerial supervision from suppliers and creditors. In selling, farmers are faced with increasing pressures and incentives to standardize product quality and to gear large and regular volumes of product supplies to particular market outlets. Options in selling are being narrowed further by a reduced number of buyers and by disappearance of traditional open markets. Many producers are finding it more and more desirable to have a specific sales outlet in sight before making production decisions. How much managerial independence has been lost by farmers varies widely among enterprises and areas of the country. The shift of entrepreneural functions off the farm has been greatest for poultry and some specialty crops. Farmers in the Midwest appear to have retained more decision-making latitude than farmers in other areas, but their traditional types of operations are being strongly challenged by integrated production-marketing systems in other sections. Other Characteristics of the Agricultural Industry Other well-known characteristics of agriculture intensify changes in number, size, and managerial independence of farmers as well as bring repeated pressures on earnings. Uncoordinated output frequently results in supplies greater than the market will absorb without sharp declines in prices. Quantities taken by the domestic market are little influenced by income or price changes, and foreign markets are |
Tags
Add tags for Economic and Marketing Information for Indiana Farmers (Mar. 29, 1968)
Comments
Post a Comment for Economic and Marketing Information for Indiana Farmers (Mar. 29, 1968)